Sam
Uden
a,
Robert
Socolow
b and
Chris
Greig
*c
aConservation Strategy Group, LLC, Sacramento, CA, USA
bDepartment of Mechanical and Aerospace Engineering, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ, USA
cAndlinger Center for Energy and the Environment, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ, USA. E-mail: cgreig@princeton.edu
First published on 7th July 2022
Integrated assessment and other macro-scale energy systems models are valuable tools for exploring alternate ways (scenarios) to decarbonize an economy. A shortcoming, however, is that most models assume new mitigation assets are conceived, permitted, financed, built and commissioned overnight. In reality, it takes multiple years to develop assets, a significant fraction of which may be abandoned or shelved because various risks and/or commercial conditions do not support the investment case. New approaches that reflect developers’ disciplined approach to capital allocation can improve scenario feasibility and inform the right policies and investments to assure deep decarbonization on-the-ground.
Recently, there has been a growing emphasis on improving scenario feasibility, with calls for greater consideration of human factors1 and finance.2 We may be the first to make a comparable plea for the consideration of private developer decision-making. In models, developers respond rationally and instantly to market signals, building new mitigation projects overnight. In reality, developers initiate a multi-year, structured decision-process to sufficiently de-risk long-lived capital investments prior to asset financing and construction. This is an area that is scarcely dealt with in the academic literature, because of a fault-line that finds most modelers of sustainable futures on one side and risk-taking project developers on the other. Yet, it presents significant implications as to the right policies to assure deep decarbonization goals.
In this Opinion, we unpack the mechanics of asset mobilization. We start by describing an important commercial concept, known as capital discipline. We show how this concept underlies two key energy transition challenges: path-dependence and the chicken-or-egg problem. Managing these challenges is essential to achieve ambitious mitigation targets. However, it is beyond the scope of, and unreasonable to expect, macro-scale systems models to incorporate features that are so granular and heterogeneous.3 We therefore introduce an approach to bridge the analytical gap, termed ‘reverse-engineering’, which is a process of interpreting energy scenarios through a developer-lens. This allows for the identification of policy and investment actions to manage path-dependence and chicken-or-egg problems, along with other execution bottlenecks. A new community of applied researchers working closely with practitioners focused on reverse-engineering could reveal critical insights needed to improve scenario feasibility.
Successful asset mobilization therefore relies on a sequence of de-risking activities and decisions, which consume considerable resources and require significant lead times. First, a sequence of pre-investment development stages takes place, progressively increasing the capital at risk, to fund project conception, initial scoping, pre-feasibility studies, feasibility studies, social and environmental reviews, permitting, and financing (Fig. 1a). Each of these stages involves multiple stakeholders and tasks and has the potential to reveal information justifying project abandonment. A significant fraction of proposals typically will be shelved or abandoned before the final investment decision (“FID”). The objective of this staged approach is to minimize capital at risk prior to the FID gate, while ensuring that any project sanctioned at the FID gate generates anticipated returns on that capital. This capital (allocation) discipline is designed to maximize returns to shareholders. It is the norm for all commercial enterprises, and it is especially deeply embedded in the decisions of asset-heavy companies. Of course, such capital discipline is compromised from time to time, especially when decision-making is impacted by incentives that are not aligned with creating company value.4
Path-dependence refers to situations where policies and investments implemented today shape, and potentially restrict, the future set of available options. For example, current global investments in clean energy are flowing almost exclusively to solar, wind, and energy efficiency measures.5 Given the lead times associated with asset development and capital formation, this may limit the potential to quickly and reliably turn to other low-carbon options, such as various clean fuels, carbon capture and storage (CCS), or nuclear power, if and when they are needed.
The chicken-or-egg problem refers to the sometimes-slow uptake of technologies because of uncertainty surrounding access to enabling infrastructure, end-use markets, and/or performance of counterparties. Chicken-or-egg problems affect new technologies, such as zero-emission vehicles and clean hydrogen, but also existing technologies, such as utility-scale renewables that are delayed or unprofitable because of transmission access risks.
Here we examine CCS, to illustrate one of many examples of the chicken-or-egg problem. The owner of a centralized industrial facility contemplating CO2 capture might allocate capital to initial scoping and prefeasibility studies, and even secure favorable government incentives, but it will never sanction the project through FID without sufficient confidence in reliable access to CO2 transport and storage capacity at an acceptable cost (Fig. 1b). Often, that confidence will need to be underpinned by a third-party agreement to take full responsibility for the CO2 during the capture project's economic life and beyond. At the same time, third-party CO2 storage operators are unlikely to invest in establishing this commercial capacity without sufficient confidence in secure supplies of CO2 priced to satisfy the targeted return on storage investment, creating an investment stalemate.6
This granular consideration of path-dependence and chicken-or-egg problems is beyond the scope of integrated assessment and other macro-scale models that describe energy transitions. As a result, existing assessments can fall short of providing feasible roadmaps or identifying climate change policies needed to put countries on realistic decarbonization pathways.
Reverse-engineering proceeds in three basic steps. First, it backcasts a mitigation option from its modeled future capacity to its current state, describing the physical asset deployment requirements at a socially-relevant spatial and temporal resolution. This downscaling could use the results from integrated assessment or other macro-scale models as a starting point. Second, it overlays the asset development sequence, describing the schedule of risk-reduction activities and decisions as well as construction times related to project delivery. Third, it determines key policy and investment interventions that could accelerate the asset development sequence and increase the likelihood that the pace of deployment implied by the model can be reached.
We demonstrate reverse-engineering by describing how an asset developer would assess the scenario of delivering one billion tonnes per year of CCS in the US in 2050 as in Princeton's Net-Zero America (NZA) study (Fig. 2, showing scenario E +).7 While NZA is a classic integrated assessment, in this particular case reverse-engineering was performed by one of us (CG) for CCS, which was then incorporated into the final results.8 In the first decade, significant upfront investments in CO2 storage and transport are directed toward the chicken-or-egg problem. At a cost of roughly $100 billion, most of the nation's CO2 storage resources are characterized and almost the entire national trunk pipeline system is built. This investment lays a foundation for the wide adoption of CO2 capture projects, ninety per cent of which come after 2030. This non-linearity suggests that ‘build it and they will come’ investments are likely to be necessary to assure feasible paths to net-zero by ambitious future dates, like 2050.
![]() | ||
Fig. 2 Required investments to solve the chicken-or-egg problem to deliver a 1 billion tonnes/year CCS system in the US in 2050. |
In contrast, policy instruments for CCS today primarily support CO2 capture, with little parallel activity in storage or infrastructure (pipelines). Even at a large-scale, this approach is unlikely to stimulate the speed and scale of CCS adoption needed to meet ambitious goals, as it fails to address the chicken-or-egg problem. Similarly, government co-investments and/or the political prioritization of iconic, flagship demonstrations can also compromise capital discipline, by rewarding the completion of projects despite their questionable long-term viability.
Storage and transport investments are arguably the most important set of interventions to de-risk CCS investment decision-making, but there are other no-regrets, ‘system-oriented’ interventions that would increase the odds of rapid and broad-scale adoption, including: streamlining regulatory processes leading to permits; performing CO2 spur pipeline routing studies; sorting out long-term liability; performing or supporting the preparation of environmental impact assessments; facilitating consensus-building and land-owner access negotiations in local communities; and providing incentives based on tons of CO2 that are captured and stored.
We note that incumbent developers may downplay certain system-oriented interventions. For example, an incumbent's access to regional resource data and ability to navigate complex regulations could create competitive advantages over new market entrants. It is in the incumbent's interest to crowd-out competition. In contrast, the rationale for system-oriented interventions is to achieve economy-wide deep decarbonization on a relatively rapid time schedule, by crowding-in competition. This implies a needed role for governments to execute strategic investments and policies.
Reverse-engineering may reveal other structural challenges related to practicable optionality. For example, a plan to pivot to CCS in the event that a renewables-heavy pathway falters must not disregard the potential for significant contraction in oil and gas production and consumption during the time before the pivot. Diminished asset values and revenues for oil and gas companies may well reduce their appetite to invest in CCS. To preserve a pivot to CCS, planners could adopt clear, transparent, and durable policies and regulations that drive oil and gas producers to coordinate the phase down of their unmitigated production with their switch to CCS and renewables portfolios.
This journal is © The Royal Society of Chemistry 2022 |