Klaus S
Lackner
*a,
Stephanie H
Arcusa
*b,
Habib
Azarabadi
c,
Vishrudh
Sriramprasad
a and
Robert
Page
b
aCenter for Negative Carbon Emissions, School of Sustainable Engineering & the Built Environment, Arizona State University, Tempe, Arizona, USA. E-mail: klaus.lackner@asu.edu
bCenter for Negative Carbon Emissions, Global Futures Laboratory, Arizona University, Tempe, Arizona, USA. E-mail: sarcusa@asu.edu
cLead Knowledge Analyst – CCUS and Carbon Removal, Boston Consulting Group, USA
First published on 5th October 2023
Life cycle analysis (LCA) is deeply embedded in carbon accounting. LCA is valuable for qualitatively understanding technologies’ environmental footprints. However, ambiguities and insatiable data requirements make it ill-suited for quantitative analysis. Fortunately, accounting without LCA is possible, for example, by demanding that for every ton of carbon coming out of the ground, another ton must be sequestered. This “Carbon Takeback Obligation” (CTBO) policy would eliminate the need for tracking carbon through supply chains. With all supply chains already carbon balanced, it is sufficient to quantify the amount of carbon sequestered without subtracting upstream emissions. Our modeling shows that once full carbon neutrality is demanded, market forces alone will eliminate counterproductive sequestration technologies, approaches that release more CO2 than they store. Complications arise during the transition where some carbon extraction is not yet balanced out by sequestration, as under some policies, counterproductive technologies could be introduced solely to game the system. We explore the economics of four transition pathways: a simple CTBO, a CTBO combined with permits required for all unbalanced carbon, a CTBO combined with a futures market, and permit-future hybrid schemes. A simple CTBO that does not add an economic burden on unmitigated carbon would incentivize low-cost, counterproductive technologies. Contrastingly, a CTBO policy that includes permits and/or futures will render such technologies uneconomical at any point in the transition. A policy with controlled futures would allow for rapid permit phaseout. Hybrid systems could lessen the initiation shock and bridge the transition time when market demand exceeds sequestration capacity.
Broader contextAchieving net zero carbon dioxide emissions through carbon sequestration will require tracking carbon. Current carbon accounting practices use Life Cycle Analysis (LCA) to trace emissions through supply chains using the scope 1, 2, and 3 emission accounting framework. The need for LCA emerges because of the hidden decision that neither the fossil carbon producer nor the end consumer should be responsible for emissions. As a result, LCA tries to decide which businesses in the supply chains are responsible. However, LCA cannot make such attributions consistently and fairly because it is a qualitative tool used for quantitative purposes. Fortunately, carbon accounting without LCA is possible, for example, by only focusing on carbon and demanding that for every ton of carbon coming out of the ground (e.g., coal, oil, gas, calcinated limestone), another ton must be sequestered. Known as the “Carbon Takeback Obligation” (CTBO), such a policy eliminates the need for tracking carbon through supply chains. Market forces eliminate counterproductive sequestration technologies, approaches that release more CO2 than they store, at full carbon neutrality. However, the transition can be gamed, so interim guardrails like permits or futures must be introduced. LCAs are insufficient; subsidies and tax credits distort the market. |
LCA is a tool that traces material flows, emissions, and environmental damages through supply chains. It requires detailed data on vast swaths of the economy to determine the environmental impact, including the CO2, of an entity, product, or service.1 CFP is a more limited form of LCA focused on determining greenhouse gas emissions, typically reported as CO2 equivalent (CO2-eq) emissions. LCAs and CFPs guide product, service, and process design. However, trying to quantitatively untangle the CO2-eq emission contributions from all supply chains ending in a particular product is notoriously difficult. This raises the question of whether LCA or CFP techniques offer the best approach to carbon accounting. In 1993, Udo de Haes feared that “LCA may become too dominant, superseding other well-functioning policy”.2 This fear may have been prescient, as today, LCA and CFP have surged in use as the “best practice” for carbon accounting, crowding out other approaches. LCA is used for greenhouse gas inventories and certifying carbon sequestration.
While LCA and CFP are powerful methods to understand a system qualitatively,3 in this paper, we make the case that neither LCA nor CFP are adequate quantitative accounting tools for the foundation of a net-zero climate policy. Their well-known subjectivity, inaccuracy, incomparability, complexity, and incompleteness make it a challenge, if not impossible, to assign carbon liabilities accurately.2,4–8 We further make the case that given the right regulatory setting, LCA is not necessary for carbon accounting in the certification of carbon sequestration. We propose a more reliable approach that avoids incorporating LCA techniques into accounting tools.
Under a finite budget, the rate of all CO2 emissions must go to zero or be canceled out by activities that sequester an equivalent amount of carbon. There are only three options: (1) eliminate fossil fuels through substitution, increased efficiency, and reduced consumption, (2) prevent CO2 from being emitted at the source through point source capture and subsequent sequestration, and (3) remove unabated and legacy carbon from the environment through carbon dioxide removal (CDR).
It is unlikely that any one of these options will dominate climate stabilization. The last 30% of emissions avoidance or substitution will be challenging due to cost and technology availability.14 Point source capture is not an option for distributive uses of fossil carbon14 and is also not 100% efficient.15 Apart from entirely stopping activities that use fossil carbon or producing synthetic fuels from other carbon sources, the remaining option is neutralizing the emissions through CDR. In essence, CDR must be purchased for every emission that cannot be eliminated. This requires an inventory of the remaining CO2 emissions and an accounting methodology that makes it possible to generate certificates of sequestration to represent the carbon sequestered.
When the amount of carbon recorded by a registry of sequestered carbon catches up with a registry of fossil fuels like the Global Registry of Fossil Fuels,16 the world has achieved a net-zero carbon economy. This situation requires careful tracking of carbon fluxes, either emissions and removals via CDR or carbon injection (i.e., fossil fuel extraction) and sequestration from point sources and the environment. Current discussions suggest that LCA and CFP will be deeply involved in the associated accounting.
The use of scopes for the compilation is a growing practice. On one level, it is growing as more and more corporations are pledging net-zero goals and using the standards devised by The Greenhouse Gas Protocol initiative.20 According to the Climate Disclosure Project, the Greenhouse Gas Protocol is the most widely used accounting standard.† On another level, the scopes framework is increasingly recommended for community accounting. For example, The Greenhouse Gas Protocol initiative also produced the Global Protocol for Community Scale Emissions Inventories,21 defining scopes based on geography rather than based on control. In doing so, the geographical scopes can be aggregated nationally. Switching to geographical scopes solved one of the major pitfalls with control-based scopes that could not be aggregated from one level to another.22
An example where LCA accounting could apply is direct air capture with subsequent injection of the captured CO2 into a deep saline aquifer. A different example would measure the amount of carbon stored in an agroforestry project for carbon sequestration. In both cases, LCA accounting would have to establish the net carbon sequestered after subtracting the CO2-eq emissions incurred in the operations and supply chains. This requires large datasets to characterize the entire supply chain.
Any accounting tool will require data. However, by demanding information about the associated supply chains, LCA relies on gathering vast amounts of data of many different types from many sources.4,7 This imposes a penalty in terms of cost and labor for collecting quality data. Costs and quality are tradeoffs suggesting that many LCAs are hindered by low data quality. Furthermore, because of the breadth of data required, every LCA will depend on the quality and completeness of the work of others, which is difficult to verify and often involves different standards in different countries. LCA has limited control over the quality of the input data without international efforts to produce specialized, standardized, and reusable databases specific to the LCA method.7,31 By drawing cautious conclusions, LCA practitioners compensate for poor-quality data.32 Another challenge is frequent changes in the workings of the supply chains starting from substitutions in the energy supplies through changes in consumer behavior. Therefore, LCA data cannot be considered static and must be continuously updated.
In addition to data issues, LCA is a subjective method in various ways. Performing an LCA requires drawing boundaries, whether the analysis uses an input–output or process-based approach. Despite guidance on approaching boundary setting, what to include or exclude remains a decision.8 These decisions depend on the researcher's motivation, data availability, and considerations of costs and labor.33 Truncation errors, the numeric gap between the reported and actual figures, arise from boundary setting, meaning that not all emissions are accounted for.34 For example, Crawford found that truncation errors in process analysis could amount to 87% compared to approaches that combine input–output and process-based approaches, the so-called hybrid approaches.35
Calls for hybrid approaches solve some boundary selection issues but introduce others. Namely, the need for even more data of good quality36 – one of the critical issues with LCA in the first place.35 Accounting ought to be objective and repeatable to support verification, which is untrue if LCA methodologies allow ad hoc choices. Even if choices are gradually standardized, they are standardized in a political environment that creates winners and losers. Someone's scope 1 is someone else's scope 2 or 3. While some of this may be unavoidable, LCA tends to exacerbate this problem.
Moreover, performing an LCA for the certification of carbon sequestration introduces a time preference for the variables used in the accounting. For example, the value of temporary sequestration is still debated.37–39 The shorter the time preference, the higher the value of temporary sequestration.40 For example, in their LCA of building materials, Mequignon et al. had to settle on a time preference to calculate the carbon footprint of building materials and how they are affected by the lifespan of the building.41 Lack of consensus on time preference from standards or in the academic literature5,7 is an argument against using an accounting method that requires choosing a time preference.
Furthermore, by putting different greenhouse gases on the same footing through the global warming potential (GWP), LCAs introduce more subjectivity and uncertainty. GWPs cannot be directly measured but are constructs of climate computer models and consequently change with every IPCC assessment.42 In addition to these conceptual and methodological problems, GWPs introduce strong time preferences into these comparisons.6,43–47
Another issue with the verifiability of LCA is how to define a baseline which is often necessary for determining avoided emissions in sequestration and inventory accounting. The least contentious baseline in inventory accounting is the inventory at the start of accounting. However, it is generally not true that emissions would not change absent climate action. This forces the LCA practitioner to create a baseline based on a counterfactual scenario considering political, economic, technological, and social changes. As a result, setting the baseline can be challenging.6 Estimates of net sequestration typically involve counterfactuals because the net amount of carbon sequestered depends on assumptions about what would have happened without these activities. What would have happened to the land if there had not been any agroforestry? Could the renewable electricity applied to the direct air capture system be better used to avoid the firing of a fossil fuel-powered power plant?
For example, Hawkins et al. performed an LCA to account for carbon sequestered in different construction materials.48 They developed two “what-if” scenarios to estimate carbon sequestration in timber. One optimistically included the regrowth of the original forest, and one pessimistically did not. The authors found that the LCA resulted in net carbon sequestration in the former and a net increase in emissions in the latter. Verifiers could not determine the sign of the effect without recourse to hindsight. Over the decades, relying on counterfactual baselines has been considered impossible to verify because counterfactuals cannot be observed.49–51 Counterfactuals get less accurate over time because they are “alternate timelines” instead of projections into the future that can be adjusted as the future catches up to the projection.
For LCA to get more accurate, the amount and precision of data required grows very rapidly. There are indications that improving LCA accuracy already encounters rapidly diminishing returns. For example, the debate over the carbon footprint of corn ethanol, which is like certifying avoided carbon in carbon sequestration, has not improved over decades. Systematic issues involving the subjective choice of boundaries and lack of accurate data contribute to the problem. A review of early estimates ranged from 55–125 gCO2-eq MJ−1, representing a 32% reduction to a 20% increase in emissions in using ethanol compared to gasoline.52 Different choices of boundaries in part explain the large span. In a later review based on updated datasets and technological improvements, Liska et al. reported the best estimated intensity of 38–48 gCO2-eq MJ−1, representing a 48–59% reduction in emission.53 Even though this approach settled on a particular set of boundaries, the range is still 23% of its median value and, therefore, inadequate for quantitative accounting. From 2009 onwards, the impact of land use change started to be incorporated into the LCA, raising the carbon intensity and drawing questions about which impacts should be included.54 In a recent review, Scully et al. reported a range of 37.6–65.1 gCO2-eq MJ−1 (a range of 54%)55 which was then questioned by Spawn-Lee et al. based on their choices regarding the land use impact.56
There are ways of reducing uncertainties. Collecting more data with different types of equipment and careful sensitivity analysis4 can help constrain the uncertainty range. A major challenge with LCA is that people's worldviews affect how boundaries tend to be drawn. Therefore, better data alone cannot constrain the range, and no model can produce a definitive assessment6 – only the reconciliation of world views.57 Estimating the net climate effects of alternative actions engender multiple perspectives and evaluation frameworks, yielding divergent outcomes that can be equally plausible.58
The range of values also raises the question of what results to use for the certification of carbon sequestration. Several studies have pointed out that carbon removal must remove more than it emits,59,60 which they call the “net negativity” criteria. In this paper, we use the term “counterproductive” to indicate that a sequestration method sequesters less carbon than it causes to emit. Such counterproductive methods are net carbon positive and would exacerbate climate change. To ascertain carbon negativity, all emissions upstream and downstream of the process must be quantified,60 including those resulting from market changes.59 As previously discussed, tracing those emissions through the entire supply chain is a considerable challenge and fraught with ambiguity.
The subjectivity and uncertainty also call into question whether the results of an LCA on two different types of methods (e.g., DACS and afforestation) are comparable. Some boundary choices like cradle-to-grave can help in cross-comparisons. Others may lend themselves to obfuscation. In a review of 36 biochar LCAs, Terlouw et al. found that GWP impacts could not be compared since each LCA used specific boundary conditions, different functional units, and parameters.61 If agreement cannot be reached for different analyses within a single sequestration technology, comparisons amongst vastly different technologies are even less likely to be useful. In an LCA study of different types of materials in automotive applications, Mair-Bauernfeind et al. concluded they could not make recommendations on which impact categories were relevant, let alone which ones to choose.62 They concluded that the selection choices were based on the researcher's motivations, yielding incomparable results. Gregory et al. compared hand drying systems and found that conclusions depended on the treatment of uncertainty.63 Impacts will invariably be different for various types of carbon sequestration activities. To treat systems equally, all possible impacts and uncertainty would need to be included, adding complexity and uncertainty to quantitative accounting. Truncating the list of impacts opens the door to vested interests questioning the equality of the certification outcome across technologies.
Over the years, many proposals and valiant efforts have been made to standardize LCA. Significant improvements were made with the Society of Environmental Toxicology and Chemistry (SETAC) in the 1990s2, the Global CO2 Initiative in the 2010s3, and what will come out of the International CCU Assessment Harmonization Group. Yet, despite the efforts, the issues of subjectivity, inaccuracy, incomparability, and incompleteness discussed above persist (and will continue to persist) because of the nature of the tool. LCA has limitations that may be acceptable when the goal is qualitative (i.e., gathering information on a process) but not quantitative (i.e., for certification of sequestration or inventory accounting). The tool is complex, and the complexity is increasing.31 More data would help some issues64 but will hit limits.
Moving responsibility all the way upstream has many advantages.65,66 It makes accounting much easier. Carbon coming out of the ground is mostly already well measured in national databases, as much of it is a commercial commodity subject to tax rules or other fees like royalties that necessitate quantification. It involves a much smaller number of entities than the alternative to put the responsibility on the physical emitter of greenhouse gases and could also be done without recourse to LCA. The sheer number of small emitters renders accounting at the emission point impractical. The current system, which pins the responsibility on the entities that largely pass the carbon through, poses the most accounting difficulties and requires LCA. The introduction of accounting scopes reflects these difficulties. Companies are supposed to keep track of scope 2 and 3 emissions which they have no control over. Scope 3 emissions can reach 6–90% of a sector's emissions,67–71 which for the fossil fuel industry equals to more than 92% of the world's CO2 emissions.72 In our view, the simplification of upstream accounting justifies separating carbon accounting from greenhouse gas accounting.
Upstream accounting reduces the dependence on methods that are subjective, difficult to apply, costly, require vast amounts of data, and yet result in significant uncertainty. Such methods create risks for the storage operators, greenwashing from those not playing fair, and a deflection of responsibility from those who ought to be cleaning up the carbon mess. Unclear rules will make it easy for claims to be made without a straightforward way to stop fraud. These issues will limit our ability to reach net zero. Both from the perspective of the attribution of responsibility and the quantification of carbon sequestration for certification, which will then support net-zero claims. Those are some reasons for limiting LCA to qualitative planning and design roles and moving quantitative accounting upstream.
The collected carbon would have to be stored in a well-delineated reservoir. The carbon addition to this reservoir must be demonstrated, documented, and its persistence monitored. This would form the basis of methodologies that account for carbon sequestration.76,77 Ideally, sequestration would be effectively permanent; therefore, short-term sequestration would be required to be transferred to a subsequent more long-term reservoir.66,77 Verified sequestration would generate a certificate of sequestration that could be used to cancel out carbon extraction and carbon release from sequestration, including deliberate extraction, accidental extraction (e.g., methane lost from a coal mine), byproduct extraction (e.g., as in the case of calcination of limestone), and losses from sequestration.
A non-permanent sequestration site would have to be a monitored reservoir, for which the storage operator agrees that any loss of carbon from the reservoir is treated like any other carbon release and thus must be matched by a new certificate of sequestration.66,77 In a scenario that relies on short-term sequestration, carbon removal would remain an ongoing operation even after all fossil fuel extraction ceased. Certification would be an ongoing effort with checks and guarantees.
It is difficult to envision a scenario in which transfers from short-term sequestration are guaranteed for the millennia required to balance the carbon budget.78 Therefore, all carbon should eventually transfer to permanent sequestration to avoid the cost of continuous monitoring and re-sequestration and prevent a termination shock. Such sequestration must be declared permanent immediately or after some trial period based on scientific principles, which is the only assurance one can give on timescales exceeding human civilization.79 The advantage of allowing non-permanent monitored sequestration with an associated guarantee of re-sequestration is that it allows a more rapid approach to carbon neutrality and net negative carbon economies. The advantage of permanent sequestration is that it stops the long-term liabilities of storage operators. This move to permanent sequestration is nearly unavoidable. The practical requirement of sequestration duration, which is to be guaranteed by a certificate of sequestration, is tens of thousands of years and thus well beyond the lifetime of human institutions.
First, we can avoid using the GWP to create equivalence between greenhouse gases. Methane and nitrous oxide are far more powerful greenhouse gases than CO2, but the quantities are much smaller. Moreover, they act very differently. CO2, once put out, stays in the surface environment for tens of thousands of years.80 There is little to be gained by mitigating other greenhouse gases before CO2 emissions have reached near zero.81 Carbon extraction and release are concentrated in a few places making accurate accounting relatively easy. In contrast, methane and nitrous oxide emissions are highly diffuse, making accounting inherently difficult. By separating the accounting of the largest source of greenhouse gases from the rest, we can take advantage of the inherently easier accounting. By making it easier to balance the carbon budget, we increase the value of curtailing other greenhouse gases, especially methane. In a world where the CO2 level keeps rising, worrying about the difference between CO2 and CO2-eq concentrations is not helpful. On the other hand, if CO2 levels are stabilized or even reduced, avoiding climate forcing through short-lived greenhouse gases becomes extremely valuable.
Second, by focusing on carbon extraction, we can avoid the complexity of tracking many sources of CO2 emissions. As mentioned before, it would be theoretically possible to avoid LCA if carbon sequestration came due at the actual point of CO2 release. The challenge with this approach is the vast number of places where emissions occur. Keeping track of all emissions is not practical. It is far easier to match certification against the much smaller number of points of carbon extraction. It should also be noted that not all emissions are simple to identify. For example, a waste incinerator plant can burn a mixture of biomass and waste plastics produced from fossil carbon. Not all the CO2 emitted from the plant would need to be canceled out, only the fraction associated with the fossil carbon component in the waste stream. Therefore, it is easier to clear all carbon as it comes out of the ground.
In our proposed approach, since an equal amount of carbon sequestration balances all fossil extraction, any CO2 emitted downstream from the extraction is already balanced. Everyone and everyone's activities are carbon neutral. Carbon used upstream in the supply chain of generating certificates of sequestration, for example, in collecting and processing the CO2, is also covered by a certificate of sequestration and thus is properly accounted for. The cost of balancing out carbon releases in the supply chain for generating a certificate of sequestration is added to the cost of the certificate. Suppose it turns out that generating a certificate of sequestration for a ton of CO2 requires more than one certificate in its generation, in other words, the process is counterproductive or lacks carbon negativity. In that case, the technology is not competitive. It thus could not be used even on the margin of such a system. The cost of a new certificate must be higher than the total cost of the implicitly included certificates, meaning it has to be less than one certificate. Identifying where precisely in the supply chain these additional emissions reside and how big they are may be challenging. Still, in a world that balances carbon at the source, cheating on the life cycle carbon balance is impossible. LCA practitioners may be able to help identify the sources of the carbon losses and improve the overall carbon efficiency of the process through better design, but their services are not needed to ensure that carbon is accounted for.
A significant advantage is avoiding the need for LCA in the monitoring and accounting schemes. This does not mean that LCA is useless. Quite the contrary, the business developer selling certificates must understand the LCA of the product. Otherwise, they might end up in a situation where upstream emissions make success impossible.
The advantage of the first set of pathways is that the transition starts slowly, and people, institutions, and firms can gradually adjust to the necessary changes. By contrast, if responsibility for the carbon is immediately put on the carbon extractor, the cost of fossil carbon will instantly rise, creating a shock to the economy like the one seen in past and current energy crises. The disadvantage of a gradual phasing-in of liability is that it creates a “moral hazard” because it incentivizes firms to spend down their carbon resources as quickly as possible. Indeed, it might promote a run to the exits and drive-up fossil fuel consumption in the short term. It also makes it difficult to ensure that one does not encourage counterproductive sequestration technologies.
Even if one gives companies time to perform sequestration, the liability for balancing carbon could start instantly. This would result in a financial shock to the existing system. One may have to ease this shock by giving tax breaks, subsidies, or, as we will discuss, introducing permits to lower the initial cost. On the other hand, immediate liability creates a clear incentive to minimize emissions from the start. It also is not unfair and reduces the advantage given to fossil fuel producers over other energy producers. From a fairness perspective, one can argue that climate change was not understood in the past and that there is no need to punish past behavior. However, today no one can argue that carbon extraction is harmless. If CO2 is a waste stream that needs to be cleaned up,82 nobody should be able to avoid this requirement. Paying for it at the point of extraction may well be the easiest way to handle this problem.
At present, α is very small, but if the climate is to be stabilized, it will have to rise to α = 1. If stabilization is to occur at a level lower than the peak reached (i.e., if societies wish to lower the atmospheric CO2 concentration), then α will have to be larger than one for at least some time. Any policy guiding the transition to a carbon neutral economy will result in a time trajectory α(t) that starts from a small value, may overshoot α = 1, and eventually asymptotes to α = 1. Policies could proscribe the α(t) trajectory, or use other levers to shape it.
The class of policies we consider rests heavily on requiring CO2 sequestration at the point of carbon extraction. This is often called a carbon takeback obligation (CTBO) by the fossil carbon extractor.73–75 The extractor ultimately must pay for the sequestration that balances the carbon extraction but may fall short of that initially. In other words, the initial takeback obligation is only a fraction of the carbon taken from the ground. We will refer to the ratio of carbon sequestered via such a takeback obligation per unit of carbon extracted as αt. The numerical value of αt is expected to result from regulatory policies, and we assume it to be uniform across all types of extraction. A central premise of our approach is that it is possible to sequester carbon from many different sources, including the environment, resulting in a uniform carbon sequestration price across different technologies. Therefore, it is not necessary to differentiate the takeback obligation of different extractors. Since the ratios α and αt share the same denominator, and sequestration to cancel out concurrent fossil carbon extraction as part of a takeback scheme is a part of the overall sequestration, we find that α ≥ αt. The two ratios need not be equal. For example, voluntary or government action may drive additional carbon sequestration to cancel out past emissions. In that case, α > αt.
By initially oversupplying the market with permits, the transition from today's economy to a carbon-controlled economy avoids a price shock. The carbon board, in effect, controls the sequestration price by adjusting the permit supply. By limiting the supply of permits, the carbon board would indirectly control αt. The price of permits and certificates could initially be small. It would increase as the supply of permits is gradually reduced. In this approach, permits discourage the unnecessary use of fossil carbon and provide a financial incentive for carbon sequestration. If permit prices are high enough to stimulate sequestration, their supply can be gradually reduced as the sequestration industry grows and becomes more mature. A carbon board that sets the permit price would, in effect, have introduced a tax. If it had set the supply of permits instead, it would have created a cap-and-trade system. However, the permit system is more flexible and can navigate between extremes.
The permit scheme has some of the same benefits as the new CTBO described by Jenkins et al., where the stored fraction escalates predictably toward 100%.74 In the permit scheme, the carbon board can announce the change in the number of permits and set the trajectory.
As we will show below, a simple carbon takeback obligation makes it difficult to weed out counterproductive sequestration technologies that turn out to be profitable. However, in a permit scheme, counterproductive technologies would never be profitable. Allowing such technologies to take hold encourages operators to extract money from climate mitigation policies without any intent or path toward carbon negativity.
A challenge to the permit scheme that was already noted by Lackner et al. is the accumulation of large revenues.66 This problem could be fixed by asking the carbon board to gradually convert permits into certificates of sequestration or futures of certificates of sequestration. The other suggestion, to give the proceeds out as a windfall to the public may create an awkward incentive to ensure that permits are not phased out to protect a windfall that is supposed to disappear. Many have proposed carbon dividends to mitigate climate change (e.g., ref. 83 and 84), but once benefits are established, they become difficult to stop (e.g., governments relying on tax revenue from fossil fuel use to pay for social services). Fossil carbon must be cleaned up or phased out as quickly as possible, not supported and extended in time. The permit scheme creates the possibility of a rapid transition. It is possible to combine the permit scheme with an approach that relies on controlled futures of certificates of sequestration in lieu of actual certificates of sequestration. This hybrid approach would create significant flexibility in responding to market failures and glitches but would require a politically independent carbon board.
In the first year of introducing this hybrid scheme, the permit supply could be intentionally large to keep costs down and solely focus on phasing in an accounting scheme. Then the carbon board could rapidly reduce the number of available permits. This requires an expiration date on permits to avoid hoarding past cheap permits. The rising price would encourage the introduction of a mixture of certificates of sequestration and controlled futures of certificates of sequestration to take on a rapidly growing market fraction. After a relatively short time, five to ten years, the only role of the permits would be to assure some price stability in the face of sudden impacts on the markets.
The permit scheme differs from the simple takeback obligation by demanding payment for all carbon from the start. Specifically, it demands a permit's price equal to that of a certificate of sequestration. An alternative would be to augment the takeback obligation scheme with a carbon tax on the unmitigated fraction of the extracted carbon.74 If that tax were equal to the price of a certificate of sequestration, it is effectively a permit scheme. In a market-driven system, storage operators would price their certificates right at the cost of the tax. When sequestration supply exceeds demand, competition among storage operators would set the price. The advantage of the permit scheme over the tax is that the carbon board can adjust the permit supply to take advantage of the decreasing sequestration cost. Once set, taxes tend to persist, creating an obvious market failure.
Lastly, not all sequestration needs to be tied to fossil carbon extraction. Indeed there is a need to remove carbon from the environment to reduce the already high CO2 concentrations in the atmosphere. Carbon accounting and the resulting certificates of sequestration could be used to eliminate excess carbon in the environment. CDR and sequestration technologies used for this purpose are generally called negative emissions technologies (NETs). Governments, private institutions, and even individuals could purchase certificates of sequestration that are not used to cancel out concurrent fossil fuel extraction. Such voluntary efforts are outside the regulatory market. They could support higher prices and subsidies for technology development without distorting incentives in the regulatory market. Such a market is beginning, as evidenced by advance purchases made by Frontier Climate and Microsoft.
This then raises the question of how a system can be stabilized in the early days against such developments when α ≪ 1. Will it require a life cycle approach, or can it move through the early stage without encouraging counterproductive technologies? The following simple model aims to shed light on this question.
Let C be the rate at which carbon is extracted, and S the rate at which it is stored. A policy results in sequestration balancing out a fraction α of all carbon extracted. Hence
S = αC | (1) |
C − C0 = εS | (2) |
We find
C = C0 + εS = C0 + αεC | (3) |
(4) |
Based on this analysis, we can compute the net emission E, which has a baseline value E0. Staying with the same carbon units as before, we find that
E0 = C0 | (5) |
(6) |
We assume that we can break the carbon cost into an intrinsic cost of the unit process plus the implicit costs arising from the supply chain, which we can estimate because we know how much CO2 we will have to sequester in total.
k = k0 + αεk | (7) |
(8) |
(9) |
There is another heuristic to explain the formula for the cost that becomes visible after expanding out the geometric sequence implied by eqn (8),
k = k0 + k0(αε) + k0(αε)2 + k0(αε)3 + … | (10) |
With this form, we can now study what happens if someone is trying to introduce a new technology to solve the problem. The new technology differs from the old, in that it has a different value for and for ε → ε′. However, this will not affect all terms in the series, because the new technology has not yet permeated through the entire supply chain but is limited to the direct effort at the end of the chain. Therefore, we can estimate the new cost of the newly introduced technology as
(11) |
(12) |
Starting from the observation:
(13) |
k = k0 + αεk | (14) |
(15) |
Δx = x′ − x. | (16) |
(17) |
(18) |
(19) |
(20) |
Indirect costs in the permit scheme are different from those in the simple carbon takeback obligation because the indirect carbon sequestration costs include the costs of the necessary permits which are by definition equal to the cost of a certificate of sequestration, i.e., the indirect cost of permits is k as well.
Therefore,
k = k0 + αεk + (1 − α)εk | (21) |
k = k0 + εk | (22) |
(23) |
Again we can expand k into a geometric series
k = k0 + k0ε + k0ε2 + k0ε3+ … | (24) |
(25) |
(26) |
(27) |
0 > r(1 − ε) + (ε′ − ε) | (28) |
(29) |
(30) |
k = k0 + αε(k − s) | (31) |
In the case of the permit scheme, the same argument can be made because the cost of the permit and that of the subsidized sequestration still must match. Again, the analysis can treat the subsidized cost, as if it were a real cost.
There are more complicated cases. For example, one could demand that a fraction α of the extracted carbon is matched by subsidized sequestration and that any further sequestration is not subsidized. In that case, the cost structure of the permit scheme would change and does not follow a simple geometric series anymore. A weird situation arises when the effective cost of sequestration after subsidy turns out to be negative, in that case one would in effect encourage fossil fuel extraction for the purpose of generating profits on carbon sequestration.
In the presence of subsidies, the lowest cost of a new competitor is not limited to zero anymore, it could be as low as −s. This means r is not bound from below at −1, it could now drop well below that, especially if k0 is small but still positive. This in turn means that counterproductive technologies can no longer be suppressed by economic incentives alone.
We understand that subsidies can help a nascent industry to grow. However, we propose that certificates of sequestration for canceling out fossil carbon should not be subsidized because subsidies open the door to counterproductive sequestration technologies, as shown. However, introducing a subsidized industry for NETs might be of practical interest as it would allow subsidies for advancing new technologies, without biasing the carbon takeback market.
Finally, we note that in analyzing economic incentives, it does not matter whether the carbon is sequestered immediately, or whether the sequestration service that has been purchased is a promise for sequestration at a future date. The indirect costs would still accrue in a similar manner.
For any policy that completely balances carbon either at the point of extraction or at the point of emission, LCA accounting is unnecessary. The purpose of LCA accounting is to keep track of carbon in the supply chains between the points of extraction and emissions. If the problem is taken care of on either end, this tracking is unnecessary. We made the point that upstream balancing at the point of extraction involves a far smaller number of stakeholders and most of the accounting necessary is already performed for other purposes like calculating royalties and taxes. We therefore suggest upstream balancing at the point of extraction.
Once all of the carbon extraction must be balanced, counterproductive sequestration technologies, i.e., technologies that release more carbon in the supply chains than they sequester, are economically unviable. However, during the transition some policies inadvertently could encourage counterproductive sequestration. Others would prevent it. One simple scheme that prevents counterproductive sequestration demands certificates of sequestration or permits for all carbon extracted and released from storage. By charging equally (either through a certificate or a permit), the cost of carbon sequestration must pay for all the carbon released in its supply chain and therefore counterproductive sequestration is economically unviable.
By introducing permits, the system avoids the need for LCA and is safe from being gamed by counterproductive technologies. Adding controlled futures, i.e., a firm promise of future sequestration, introduces a hybrid scheme that separates the time constant for phasing in the accounting from the time constant for developing the new sequestration infrastructure. The goal of the permits is to ameliorate the initiation shock, the controlled futures are designed to bridge the transition time in which the sequestration capacity falls short of market demand. Softening the initiation shock will take a few years, building the necessary infrastructure will take decades.
Subsidies or tax credits can help in the early development of a technology. Unfortunately, they tend to distort the market and open the door to counterproductive sequestration technologies. However, they are unnecessary. The large and currently unmet demand for negative emissions, i.e., the sequestration of legacy carbon, has reached a level that this becomes the natural place for governments to support new technologies and help them drive their costs down. It is likely that driving down the CO2 concentration in the atmosphere will be paid for by public funds. If this effort starts now and is distinct from balancing the carbon for current fossil fuel consumption, it will not only jumpstart the reduction of CO2 into the atmosphere, but it will also incubate new technologies that need help in moving from early stages to commercially viable approaches without unnecessarily creating incentives for counterproductive sequestration.
The approach outlined in this paper presents a different perspective of climate mitigation and carbon management. It focuses on inputs and outputs rather than the convoluted pathways through the economy. It is inherently simpler. To implement such a system requires regulatory frameworks. These frameworks must address the issuance of permits for fossil carbon extracted and lacking a certificate of sequestration; standards to certify sequestration and provide guarantees for its permanence; and standards for controlled sequestration futures. Testing this approach with storage operators and jurisdictions would be the next step, which would yield data for a quantitative comparison to the current approach.
Footnotes |
† In 2016, 92% of Fortune 500 companies responding to the CDP used GHG Protocol directly or indirectly. |
‡ In effect, this situation has arisen in the voluntary market, where there is an oversubscription of investor demand towards Climeworks and other DAC companies’ capacity. According to CDR.fyi, almost 4 million tons have been purchased but only 2% delivered as of 06/29/2023. |
This journal is © The Royal Society of Chemistry 2023 |